Monday, June 3, 2019
Effect of Earnings Decline on Crime Levels
Effect of Earnings Decline on horror LevelsModule Contemporary Issues in the UK EconomyUse an appropriate supply and consume framework to explain how a decline in earnings from legitimate work would be anticipate to affect the level of offensive activity. To what extent does evidence from the UK offer this theoretical prediction?The idea that slump earnings affect offence is not a new idea Aristotle (350 B.C.) himself said poverty is the parent of revolution and crime (pg. 32). Since past, there has been much research in the field since policymakers require this information to create effective crime-reducing policies. In novel years, conciliateing unfeigned struggle has been a significant issue since the UK is in the longest period of pay stagnation since 1855 (The Economist, 25th Oct 2014). I leave discuss the impact of fall issue on the crime rate by using an economic supply and motivation framework and comparing my findings to real evidence from UK data.Both Becke r (1968) and Freemans (1999) work make the assumption that illegals are rational economic agents and hence criminal activity can be beatled using a supply and demand framework in the same way one could a goods or services market.Economic theory states that the supply of crime depends on four components electric potential earnings from committing a successful crime (Wc), probability of being caught (p), level of punishment (S) and struggle earned from legitimate work (W). This can be shown in the following inequality(1-p)U(Wc)-pU(S)U(W)The left hand side represents the potential net benefit gained from committing the crime and the right hand side shows the utility of legitimate earnings. So the individual will commit a crime if the net benefits of committing the crime exceed the benefits of legitimate work.These doers which influence whether an individual decides to commit a crime or not can be aggregated to create the following function for Criminal Participation (CP)CP=f (Wc, P, S, W).The demand function of crime describes how the level of crime in society falls as individuals take increasing preventative measures (Cook, 1986) and therefore, the demand curve is down(prenominal) sloping. However, the level of demand for committing crimes varies depending on the type of criminal activity undertaken. Freeman (1999) differentiates between victimless(prenominal) and victims crime suggesting that victimless crime carries obvious economic gain, e.g. dealing drugs, whereas victims crime has no obvious economic benefit e.g. violent crime. However, the downward sloping demand curve for victims crime is less intuitive so most work focusses on victimless crime. It is worth noting that one of the limitations of this supply and demand model in analysing crime rates is that it does not take into account non-economic incentives i.e. the feeling of doing wrong versus earning an honest living.Having discussed how to model crime using supply and demand compend, I will a t present use these economic tools to illustrate a situation where wages are falling.If wages from legitimate work (W) fall, the supply curve will shift outwards since the opportunity cost of crime has fallen. victimization the inequality previously discussed ((1-p) U(Wc)-pU(S)U(W)), if legitimate earnings (W) fall, assuming ceteris paribus, the benefits of committing the crime are relatively higher. then more people will be willing to commit crimes. This is shown in Figure 1 as the shift from CP1 to CP2.Cantor and Land (1985) call this the want effect.As shown here, the outward shift of supply of crime (CP1 to CP2) results in an increase in the amount of crime committed (Q1 to Q2).However, there is also a fall in potential earnings from crime (Wc1 to Wc2) if wages fall, the value of consumer goods being bought is likely to fall so there are fewer valu up to(p) goods unattached to steal. This is the Opportunity Effect (Cantor and Land, 1985). So the fall in wages could actually r educe the crime level.It is difficult to gauge which effect, Opportunity or Motivation, is stronger. One factor which could affect this is whether low or high wages are falling. Machin and Meghir (2004) make this distinction by analysing the 25th wage percentile to capture lower skilled workers whose opportunity cost of committing is lower (Freeman, 1999). Machin and Meghir use data from England and Wales (1975-1996) and focus on vehicle and property crime as these are more likely to be driven by economic incentives than e.g. violent crimes.Figure 2 shows the relationship between the level of wage gain in an economy and the level of crime. The fold proximity of the points on the graph to the regression line (calculated using a weighted least squares regression) shows a relatively strong negative correlation between the variables and the slope of the regression line gave a value of -1.580 hence, as the 25th percentile wage rises by 1%, the property crime rate is expected to fall b y 1.580%.Machin and Meghirs work supports the theoretical analysis that falling wages leads to higher crime rates for low paid workers. Therefore if low wages fall, the Motivation effect exceeds the Opportunity effect.We can also look at more recent wage and crime data from the UK to see if it supports the conclusion, that falling wages leads to higher crime rates, drawn from supply and demand analysis. As shown in Figure 3, there has been a downward trend in the real wage rate in the UK since the financial crash in 2007, real wage growth was a dishonor 10% but this has fallen to -9% by 2014.Using economic theory, it is evident that if real wages fall, then revenue enhancement revenue earned by the government is likely to decrease through e.g. lower income tax income revenue. Moreover, if people have lower earnings, governments spending in transfer payments e.g. benefits is likely to rise. The situation of falling tax revenue and higher demand for world services has led to a worse ning budget balance so the Coalition government adopted austerity measures.This has affected many areas of public sector spending, including the police force where there have been 2.5bn in budget cuts since 2011, and an estimated 70% of these cuts have been in officer cuts (BBC News, 22nd July 2014). This leads to a fall in the probability of being caught (P) and severity of punishment (S), since severe punishments are typically more expensive. The effects on P and S are second round effects derived from falling wages. Using the CP function, one would expect that if P and S fall there is a rise in crime.However, national crime statistics introduce a reduction in the level of crime in the UK ( approximate 4)So it is evident that crime has been falling since around 1995 as shown by the Crime keep abreast for England and Wales (CSEW) data estimate. Since the financial crash, crime has fallen from around 10.5 million in 2008/2009 to 8.5 million in 2012/2013. This contradicts the concl usion made using supply/demand analysis that falling wages leads to higher crime rates. However, David Cameron argues that remaining policemen have been asked to do more with less resources and they have performed magnificently (Gill, 2013). However, critics argue that there are other factors which have reduced crime statistics.Gill (2013) points towards technological advancements as a significant reason for a falling crime rates. Firstly, car manufacturers are able to include central locking systems which makes it more difficult for criminals to break in. Secondly, car break-ins are typically a starter crime leading onto more estimable crimes such as drug dealing if fewer people are getting involved in crime at this lower level then there will be less crime overall. Thirdly, Gill (2013) highlights the way crime is reported as being a problem since there has been growth in online and high tech crime, for example, online credit card fraud, which is not taken into account in the CSE W crime statistics.Therefore, the second round effects, that falling wages/tax revenue force governments to cut police funding results in more crime, may not be felt since technological advancements have resulted in less (reported) crime.That said, the Ministry of Justice (MoJ) made a statement (2010) explaining how it planned to stabilise the number of prisoners until 2014/2015 and after this it would look at reducing the number by 3000 fewer than the figure as of 19th November 2010 (85,393). So while austerity measures have been implemented by the government, the severity of punishments has yet to fall significantly this may be other reason why the crime rate did not increase whilst wages have been falling. It will be interesting to see whether going forward now crime rates increase since the MoJ is aiming to reduce the number of prisoners.In conclusion, it is evident that a supply and demand framework to model the effect of falling wages on crime cannot fully explain the situati on we are currently in. In all fairness, Machin and Meghirs work did support these findings, however more recent wage and crime data has contradicted the expected outcome. Therefore, although using a supply and demand framework can explain the impact of falling wages on crime to an extent, other factors, such as technological developments, may also influence the crime rate and policymakers who are trying to tackle crime lead to ensure these other factors are also taken into account.BibliographyAristotle (350 B.C.E.) Politics. Translated by B. Jowett. 1999. Kitchener Batoche Books.Becker, G. (1968) Crime and Punishment An Economic Approach. Journal of Political Economy, 76 (2) 169-217.Becker, G. (1992) The Economic Way of spirit at Life. Nobel Prize transcript, Wednesday 9th December, Available from http//www.nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/economic-sciences/laureates/1992/becker-lecture.pdf Accessed 18th November 2014.Blunt, C. (2010) Imprisonment for Public Protection. House of Commo ns Debate transcript, Tuesday 23rd November, Available from http//www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/cm201011/cmhansrd/cm101123/debtext/101123-0001.htm Accessed on 20th November 2010.Cantor, D. and Land, K. C. (1985) Unemployment and crime rates in the post-World War 2 United States A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis. American Sociological Review, 50 (3) 317332.Cook, P. J. (1986) The Demand and Supply of Criminal Opportunities. Crime and Justice, 7 1-27.Crime in England and Wales Quarterly Bulletin. The Office of National Statistics online, 19th July 2012. Available from http//www.ons.gov.uk/ons/dcp171778_273169.pdf Accessed 16th November 2014.Dolphin, T. (2014) Bleak figures show a relentless slide towards a low-pay Britain. The Observer online, Sunday 19th October. Available from http//www.theguardian.com/business/2014/oct/18/economy-bleak-british-workers-technology Accessed 18th November 2014.Ehrlich, I. (1996) Crime, Punishment and Market for Offenses. The Journal of Economic P erspectives, 10 (1) 43-67.Freeman, R. (1999) The Economics of Crime. In Ashenfelter, O. and Card, D. (ed.) vade mecum of Labour Economics, 3. Amsterdam, Netherlands North Holland Publishers. pp. 3530-3571.Gill, M. (2013) David Cameron is wrong falling crime rates are not because of the magnificent police. New Statesman online, Thursday 18th July. Available from http//www. tidingstatesman.com/ government activity/2013/07/no-david-cameron-falling-crime-rates-are-not-because-magnificent-police Accessed on 17th November 2014.Machin, S. and Meghir, C. (2004) Crime and Economic Incentives. The Journal of Human Resources, 49 (4) 958-979.Police forces in England and Wales rise to the cuts challenge. BBC News online, 22nd July 2014. Available from http//www.bbc.co.uk/news/uk-28415123 Accessed 18th November 2014.Real Wages What Recovery?. The Economist online, 25th Oct 2014. Available from http//www.economist.com/news/britain/21627665-workers-continue-feel-pinch-what-recovery Accessed 18th N ovember 2014.
Subscribe to:
Post Comments (Atom)
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.